![]() |
Financial saviours? Treasury Secretary Tim Geithner; US President Barack Obama; and Federal Reserve Chair Ben Bernanke |
Review: Adam Tooze, Crashed: How A Decade of Financial Crises Changed the World
It is ten years since the great
crash of 2008. Amid the retrospectives, thoughts are turning to the
future. Presumably not wanting to throw the baby of financial profit out with
the bathwater of dodgy practices, the Economist notes gratefully that
regulation is receding while the riskiest sources of funding are
curbed. Not everyone has been so measured: a ‘golden age’ of
banking is once again on the horizon, according to Jamie Dimon, the
CEO of JPMorgan Chase. Nevertheless, where banks were once left
largely to their own devices, the Economist opines, now the
whole business of regulation is unavoidably ‘politicised.’
Surveying the financial scene it is clear that little has really
changed since the disaster of 08. For perhaps the world’s most
influential pro-market serial or at least its oldest, the lesson of
the crisis is that public ‘authority can expand’ to fill the
private vacuum. This is, if anything, an understatement for what
happened in the wake of the crash, when the US Federal Reserve
arguably became the linchpin of the financial system and the
political nerve centre of global capitalism, with profound
repercussions.
Adam Tooze has written a
compelling account of how this played out. Crashed: How a Decade
of Financial Crises Changed the World tells a two-part story in
many chapters: there is, first, a technical economic narrative based
on the mortgage securities boom of the 2000s and its eventual,
historic crash. Then there is the long story of the various
geopolitical repercussions that have followed in its wake. It takes
in the technicalities of money market funding, the botched crisis
management of the Eurozone, China’s unprecedented fiscal stimulus,
Russian revanchism, and - perhaps pivotally - the novel rescue
efforts of the US Federal Reserve.
This was not for Tooze a crisis
of the ‘real economy’ - there is scant regard for the long term
stagnation of wages that is familiar from leftist critiques of
neoliberalism. Rather Tooze’s is a story whose backdrop, laid out
in the opening third of the book, is a relatively apolitical
technology of finance. The force that determines the fateful collapse
of financial activity in 2007-08 is not, in Tooze’s telling, the
acquisition of risky assets (mortgage backed securities or
collateralised debt obligations, etc.) per se, but the liability or
funding access of the big investment banks, which was heavily skewed
towards short-term money markets and had largely divorced itself from
the prosaic traditions of bank deposits and productive investment.
What Tooze calls a ‘modern bank run’ involves large money funds
simply refusing to lend to those whose balances are cluttered with
risky debt. The panic led investors away from risk and straight
towards Treasury bills, bunds, and other safe sovereign assets. This
stampede out of private securities markets and into safe public
sector debts was presided over by political regimes of varying
technical ability and differing ideological baggage. In its turn this
would decide whether an economy recovered (China), stagnated (the US)
or burned (the eurozone).
Tooze’s construction of
agency is one of feedback between economic structure and political
agency, with each driving the formation of the other. He is admirably
critical of the type of technocratic governance produced by the
neoliberal era, less so of its ontological assumptions. In its sheer
technicality, it inevitably lacks reforming passion. Aditya
Chakrabortty has accused the book of being ‘brilliant, but
bloodless’. The criticism is largely misplaced; a certain forensic
skill is inherent in the form. More apposite would be to say there is
a certain entering into the Lebenswelt of those who made the
crisis and a empathy with its particular Weltanschauung. It’s
a cliche to say that empathy underlies historical understanding. Yet
to impute a kind of Weberian critical method of Verstehen to
the book would be to place a more complete emphasis on individual
Zweckrationalitรคt
than he really offers. At the project's base, and despite its
insistence on the real centrality of great power politics, is an
apolitical set of financial mechanisms that just... emerge. Perhaps
what Tooze really shares with his subjects is a narrative framework
of understanding in which politicians and officials improvise in the
face of vast, unforeseen, and largely accidental conflagrations.
On the spark that caused the
bank runs and the liquidity crunch - or the widespread refusal of
banks and financial institutions to lend - one could quibble with
Tooze on a technicality. If these short term money lenders were
refusing to lend to over-leveraged banks, they must have been doing
so on the basis of certain signals. And all the signals suggested
that the wave of mortgage defaults that was sweeping the US would
soon hit the MBS markets. The funding model used by the banks was to
borrow at relatively low rates from money markets and invest in
higher rate securities. The trigger may not have been collapsing
subprime securities, but the rising uncertainty caused by the obvious
chaos in the US mortgage sector. Since the entire lending structure
of the financial system – indeed, the investment structure of
capitalism per se – is based on the psychology of expectations, any
bank run will be caused not by present losses but precisely by
expected ones. The funding collapse was no different. The system saw
the defaults coming and anticipated its own demise.
At a less technical and more
historical level, Tooze’s account implies but does not explore a
critique of the political economy of homeownership in the US: the
private mortgage system that had made two thirds of US citizens into
property owners was not originally profitable. Thirty year fixed
interest rate mortgages that could be refinanced at favourable rates
meant ruin – especially in the era of high inflation – for the
large system of small banks who offered mortgages in the postwar era.
So government sponsored enterprises (GSOs) like Fannie Mae were
created as public sector entities that would buy up mortgages from
the small commercial and savings and loans banks. After the
semi-privatisation of Fannie Mae during the fiscal squeeze of the
Vietnam War, new revenue streams were found by selling on the
mortgages as assets to investors. ‘Originate and distribute’ and
the subsequent invention of mortgage-backed securities, which pooled
mortgage products into high and low risk tiers, was in part a result
of the search for profit in a lopsided and dysfunctional private
housing system.
This covers the asset side, but
what about bank liabilities? Where was the cash sourced? Formerly
respectable investment banks – Merrill Lynch, Goldman Sachs, Morgan
Chase and so on – came to specialise in MBS, but what was their
funding model? They had no depositors, so instead they would draw on
pools of funds managed by the so called money market mutual funds
(MMF). The role of commercial banks as middle men between those with
cash and those willing to invest it disappeared. Wealthy individuals
lent directly to the funds and these were drawn on by speculative
investment banks. These were later joined by commercial banks
following the abolition of New Deal banking regulations in the
Clinton era. In this way, investment banks, commercial banks and
mortgage lenders would break free of the patrician mortgage system of
the New Deal era and build their business models around each stage of
the MBS circulation system. The low interest rates of the early 2000s
allowed this private circuit of capital to fully unleash its
potential and to really dominate the semi-public GSEs. The move into
subprime tranches of mortgage debt followed the break with the GSEs:
the sale of ever more risky and exotic mortgage products was enabled
by the growth of the ratings agencies as well as the spread of
insurance facilities like credit default swaps (CDS), which covered
the holder in the event of default. CDOs repackaged and reorganised
“mezzanine” debt tranches so as to further spread the risk. The
process of risk spreading itself was taken to warrant an AAA rating
by the now infamous ratings agencies.
The granting of AAA ratings to
such assets may have been ill-considered at best, but that didn’t
stop surging demand for assets from the newly globalised economic
system. The trade surpluses of developing countries hoovered up
Treasury bills. The large institutional investors of the financial
markets were left with agency-rated private debt – especially MBS –
to put on their books. Thus, Tooze argues, while everyone in the US
worried that China would one day sell off its dollar-denominated
Treasurys, the real risk went unnoticed: the huge growth of private
sector debt in financial markets that was funded by extremely
volatile and risk-sensitive money markets. The latter was, for Tooze,
the “fully lethal mechanism” of the 2007-08 crisis.
Tooze
does not scrimp on the detail, but this is precisely what makes the
book so useful for understanding the crisis. Banks would issue
asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) via special investment vehicles
(SIV). This asset-backed paper derived its value from expected future
cash flows from the assets issued by the banks and relied on the
reputation of the bank itself. The assets were made up of debts such
as student loans, car loans, mortgages and CDOs. Thus the funding of
the banks – that is, their access to the liquidity that could keep
the whole system moving – was reliant on the reputation of their
assets unlocking short-term borrowing. The SIV could hold large
amounts of riskier, higher yield assets while issuing ‘safe’, low
yielding ABCP. The incentive was thus to expand the balance sheet and
profit from the spread between the high yield assets and the low
yield payments it made on ABCP. After 2004, Tooze explains, the SIVs
that issued the ABCPs on behalf of investment and large commercial
banks were required to hold just 10% of the capital that their
‘parent’ banks had to hold. The repo (or repurchase) markets were
the ‘most elastic’ form of funding: investment banks would
purchase a security and immediately resell it in a repo market. When
reselling the security (often t-bills), it would commit to buying it
back at a fixed price on a very short term basis – usually over
night. Investment banks selling securities on repo markets would
accept a cost (an interest payment as well as a ‘haircut’ or
discount on its nominal value) in order to access liquid cash
belonging to either other investment banks or to money market mutual
funds. Tooze explains that in exchange for $100 million in Treasurys,
a bank would receive only $98 million in cash. This meant that in the
initial securities purchase the bank was accessing 98% of its funding
via repo and fronting only 2% of its own capital. What would make the
difference, however, was a sudden sharp increase to the 2% haircut,
which would increase the bank’s own capital requirements. The risk
for under-capitalised, over-leveraged banks is clear enough, yet the
repo markets were not much monitored or regulated. When the haircut
rose steeply, as it would in 08, banks were simply cut off from
funding.
It was by no means only US
banks that were involved in this process: as Tooze explains, the
European financial system had by the mid-00s become an appendage of
the US system. European banks held half of nongovernment money market
funds by 2008 – a total of $1 trillion. It was often European
assets that made up the collateral used by SIVs in the issuance of
commercial paper. Tooze makes clear the extent to which Transatlantic
finance is a fully-integrated, transnational system. Supposedly
‘inter-continental’ flows of securities purchases, ABCPs and repo
transactions between the US and Europe would simply be moved from one
Wall Street office to another. This was an extraordinary means for
what David Harvey, echoing Marx, called the annihilation of space
through time. Cross border bank claims between the US and Europe more
than doubled in the boom of 2002 to 2007. Moreover, Asian money
tended to go through Europe first before it entered the US economy.
This was a global financial system with the US and Europe at its
heart.
Yet it was regional policy
responses which would determine the impact of the crisis. Indeed, it
is in the rush to hold sovereign debt – and Europe’s failure to
respond – that one strand of the eurozone crisis can be traced. As
automatic stabilisers kicked in in the wake of recession (including
unemployment insurance and declining government tax intake), public
sector deficits naturally grew. Whether fiscally conservative or
spendthrift, most governments were forced to borrow heavily. While
other major central banks committed to buy up the glut of government
debt that followed the recession, the ECB at first did not. Instead
it extended favourable loans (LTROs) to banks and only in 2012 bought
up bonds in secondary markets from financial investors themselves
(OMT). Thus stressed European banks moved into sovereign debt, amply
funded by ECB liquidity. The mild divergence in the yield (interest)
on eurozone member states’ government debt was an initial spur.
Greek bonds were denominated in euros, but earned slightly more than
German bunds. It seemed like a safe enough bet. It was only as it
became clear that Greece and Ireland were in serious debt trouble
that the spread on government bond yields between the core of the
eurozone and the periphery became problematic.
Less a question of scale, then,
for Tooze, the 2008 crisis was really rooted in the peculiar
conditions of the 2002-07 boom in mortgage securities lending – in
particular on the funding rather than asset side. Once the
refinancing boom of the early 2000s – sparked by Fed interest rate
cuts – had burnt itself out, the hunt was on for the next big
thing. AAA-rated MBS looked like the perfect bet: high yield, low
risk, and seemingly ever-expanding. Even as the Fed gradually raised
the rate in short term funds, long term rates failed to rise. But
what emerges as the real spark of the crisis – the seizure of the
money markets and the refusal to grant banks access to vital
liquidity – is, as Tooze says, a matter of funding, not of mortgage
defaults per se. Yet there was a wave of mortgage defaults, triggered
by those whose rates had risen while their incomes had stagnated. The
foreclosure wave had millions of victims. The job losses were in the
real economy and had complex, secular causes that stretched back
before the 2000s boom.
Financialisation itself was
rooted in the dollarisation of the world economy that took root
during the Breton Woods era and was turbo-charged by the various
shocks of the long 1970s – the Nixon Shock (ending the dollar’s
gold peg and the system of fixed exchange rates); the oil shock
(sudden, inflationary price hikes); and the Volcker Shock (a huge,
sustained increase in interest rates to kill off inflation at the end
of the 70s). The interconnections with the real economy are complex
but the results are familiar: the weakening of organised labour; the
decoupling of wages from productivity; the deindustrialisation of the
Anglo-Saxon economies; a neo-Mercantilist Germany whose wage
repression encouraged huge trade surpluses; the rise of China as the
industrial engine of the world; the integration of dominant and
subordinate economic groups of states into an extremely hierarchical,
technocratic system of governance with central bankers at its head.
The liberalisation of national economies and the ending of all kinds
of capital restrictions put a fire under the development of a foreign
exchange market (largely dollar based) that was already housed in the
City of London. The need for dollars was pervasive and only more
deeply entrenched by 2008. The most startling result of the crash was
the revelation that the Fed was not merely a bit player, tidying up
after the banks and smoothing the system, but was really the dominant
player in the entire global financial order. Thanks to existing
dollar exchange swap lines, Tooze explains, the Fed was quietly able
to pump liquidity not only into US banks, but out into the entire
world economy – and to an ailing Europe in particular.
There is a risk of course that
such an analysis lapses into conspiracy theory. The Fed’s powers
are, in a certain sense, quite accidental. Indeed, its own centrality
to the global system was not officially recognised by its governing
ideology. The Fed was supposed to finetune, to correct for certain
imbalances, to lever this way or that by controlling the short term
funds rate. When this didn’t work, however, it was clear that the
capacity and willingness to intervene was there. When the private
sector was unwilling to maintain the supply of dollars to the world
system, it turned out there was one institution that could step in,
perhaps without limits.
The latter has led to something
of an epiphany among academics. Money, we have been reminded, is
indeed political. In a clear break with the Friedmanite neoliberal
era, the question of monetary governance is no longer seen as one
simply of over or under supply. This is not to say that mainstream
economists now want a break with the era of central bank
independence. But for both left liberals and liberal technocrats,
central banks are either the potential or really existing saviours of
the financial system and the wider economy.
There are several caveats to
this: there can only be one Fed. Other central banks are not granted
equal privileges. While the Fed can support the global system by its
control of the dollar, others have more parochial concerns. They must
use the old technique of mobilising their foreign reserves in the
event of a currency run. There is also a question over the limits to
which markets will tolerate central bank intervention in secondary
sovereign debt markets to support governments’ fiscal deficits. And
then there is the question of unaccountable, unelected power. In the
enduring tension between economic governance and political
accountability that characterises liberal democracies, the new role
of a select few central banks represents an extreme kind of
technocratic governance. Less the abolition of politics per se than
its transference to corporatist, consensus-oriented, anti-popular
elite institutions. Which inevitably provoked a backlash in the form
of the extreme right of the Tea Party and the election of Donald
Trump.
One wonders if what was needed
in the crisis was not less politics but more. For a left liberal such
as Tooze, the early moves of the Obama administration cannot but seem
a missed opportunity. Had a bigger stimulus package been passed by
the government – not as a technical rescue package but as a popular
and populist measure to save the real economy – government would at
least have taken the credit. Yet as Tooze rightly observes, the Obama
administration was the inheritor of a kind of liberal macroeconomic
orthodoxy. Though clearly capable of major interventions to rescue
finance, it was ideologically incapable of a radical or popular break
to the left.
Much of the rest of Tooze’s
book is taken up with an account of the geopolitical response to the
crisis. If the economics is highly technical, the politics is oddly
conventional. There is nothing in the approach that could not be
found in the liberal intergovernmentalist turn of 1990s international
relations theory. Is there something of an elective affinity between
Tooze’s left liberalism and the much more traditional, even realist
assumptions of IR-influenced liberals like Moravcsik? Or is there a
formal limitation of this kind of macro-economic narrative history?
Then again, perhaps only a left liberal would attempt such a
narrative history in the first place. The segue (or even gear change)
from a structural and institutional analysis of the incentives
driving the boom to, first, the improvised policy around the recovery
and, finally, the subsequent social fallout may necessarily lack
theoretical integration. The narrative Tooze has chosen to construct
demands a focus on the strategic international environment of states,
the actors who attempt to advance state interests, and the domestic,
societal pressures placed on governments by interest groups. This is
not necessarily a shortcoming: the sparse theoretical backdrop allows
the substantial contrasts in state orientation to emerge all the more
clearly. There can be no mistaking that China’s
Keynesianism-on-steroids bucked the global trend and maintained
growth across the entire world economy in the early 2010s. The
eurozone’s catastrophic lost decade seems all the more self-imposed
precisely because of its divergence from the US’s early monetary
adventurism. The eurozone crisis itself emerges not as a matter of
sovereign debt, nor even really one of underlying competitive
imbalances between national economic blocs, but as failure of elite
policy.
Within all of this there is a
hidden tension: Tooze does not regard trade and capital flows between
national and regional economic units as of particular significance to
the cause of the crisis. He dispenses with the conventional
macroeconomic focus on national accounts, competitive imbalances, and
exchange rate fluctuations. The global system as an integrated whole
was in crisis. Therefore, a supposedly deracinated policy elite
emerges as the central bloc of actors who are responsible for crisis
resolution. And yet throughout, these responses are conditioned by
regional, and yes, national and state-level views as to the scale,
nature and policy implications of the crisis. Again and again the
individual actors are situated in national and regional contexts. In
the midst of the crisis, intergovernmental bargains once again come
to the fore. The sublime world of smooth financial flows, market
signals, and ‘market-conforming’ interventions is brought
clattering down to earth – first, via the coarse, improvised
intrusions of the rescue efforts and second, by the difficult
realisation that national and sectional interests would reassert
themselves against the ‘technocrats’.
Still, there is a stark lesson
in all of this: the existential threat to the neoliberal order does
not emanate wholly ‘from within' –that is, from those famous
‘internal contradictions’ of the capitalist system –but from
the political reactions (and reactionaries) it produces. Tooze’s
book points above all to a new era of intensified political
competition. And indeed, for progressive challengers to the old
hegemony, it is not necessarily the economic or ‘structural’
sphere that poses a threat to real reforms, but the politics of the
thing. For all that the book is a measured critique of the weaknesses
of the policy elite, it is quite comfortable with the machinery of
the political world that has emerged from the crisis. After all, if
the Fed can literally rescue the global financial system through
liquidity provision, it can probably fund a long-term deficit that
would finance public goods like universal healthcare. So long as a
central bank is willing to keep up sovereign bond purchases, there is
no reason that government debt should experience a sudden loss of
value and a spike in yields. Insofar as a radical government will
rely on an expansion of public debt, this is a strangely reassuring
thought. Yet the crisis has also revealed the autonomy of central
banks and may even have generated in them a sense of their own
institutional responsibilities and interests. It is unlikely that no
conservative political pressure would be brought to bear on, say, the
Bank of England if there were to be a radical left Labour government.
The key lesson of the book for those who do want to reform capitalism
is that they may be more reliant on the loyalty of these institutions
than they would comfortably like.
Tooze has produced a dazzling
account of the decade of crisis that has shaped the world in which we
now live. In the struggle to understand and to change that world, the
book will be helpful, though not perhaps in the ways radicals might
hope. As a technical description of the financial crisis it is
unmatched. As an account of political action, we must hope it is not
exhaustive.
No comments:
Post a Comment